Friday, September 9, 2016

Does Silver Have a Feasible Solution to Nix the One-and-Done?


                 The current state of affairs in National Collegiate Athletics Association (NCAA) basketball is less than ideal. First, the majority of its premier players are opting to leave for the National Basketball Association (NBA) after only one year of playing. This results in a diminished on-court product for the NBA because these young players are raw in terms of their skill level. Since they are raw and underdeveloped, they are seen as projects who take two to three years to become impactful NBA players. They are referred to as “one-and-done” players.[1]
This situation is a result of the NBA’s minimum age limit. Currently, the NBA requires players to be 19 years of age or at least one year removed from high school before becoming draft eligible.[2] Some players[3] have chosen to play overseas to earn income instead of attending college. NBA Commissioner Adam Silver has stated he would like to increase the NBA’s draft eligibility age to 20.[4] However, this would have to be bargained for in the 2017 Collective Bargaining Agreement (CBA).[5] In increasing the age limit, the NBA has an opportunity to work with the NCAA and help college basketball players. If the age limit is increased, Silver suggests the NBA may be able to subsidize college players as far as their “basic necessities,” contribute to the “actual cost of attendance gap above what the players get for their scholarships,” and also offer a more complete insurance plan.[6]  This agreement would also allow NCAA basketball players to earn income off of their own names, images, and likeness by making the NCAA abolish bylaws 15.1[7] and 12.4.1.1[8]. [9]
This paper assumes the age limit increase will occur only if the NCAA and the NBA make an agreement where the NCAA (1) abolishes bylaws 15.1 and 12.4.1.1, (2) allows the NBA to compensate players for “basic necessities” and contribute to the “actual cost of attendance gap above what the players get for their scholarships,” and (3) allows the NBA to provide a more complete insurance plan. It is an extremely enticing opportunity for players to play in the NBA because it allows them to capitalize on their draft stock and earn money for themselves or their families, who may be in poverty or experiencing financial difficulty. This option may mitigate the “one-and-done” problem.
Adam Silver believes that any solution to this problem must be through a “three-way conversation” between the NBA, NBPA (National Basketball Players Association), and NCAA.[10] Silver is proposing an agreement between massive entities to fix a key social and legal issue in NCAA basketball.
First, this paper will examine the legal framework of antitrust law. In doing so, it will analyze the various exemptions such as Major League Baseball, the Statutory Labor Exemption, and the Non-Statutory Labor exemption. It will then examine whether Adam Silver’s proposed three-way conversation would violate Section 1 of the Sherman Antitrust Act (“Act”). Most notably, it will determine whether the non-statutory labor exemption, under the factors from Mackey v. NFL, would allow for such an agreement. It will then look at whether the agreement would be legal under the rule of reason.
I.   Section 1 of the Sherman Antitrust Act
a.     Policy and Rationale
Section 1 of the Act states, “Every contract, combination in the form of trust or otherwise, or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce among the several States, or with foreign nations, is declared to be illegal. . ..”[11] Its primary purpose is to promote competition in the marketplace.[12] In the United States, competition allows the consumer to have more choices in the market, resulting in a more efficient allocation of financial resources. When there is competition, the consumer becomes important to the long-term success of a company and companies can compete for leading market position. It would be nonsensical to have a free market structure without antitrust laws because competition needs to work properly in order for capitalism to thrive.
b.     Elements of a Section 1 Claim
In sports, the courts have developed a test for determining when an agreement violates Section 1 of the Act. Three elements must exist for a Section 1 claim. First, there must be an agreement between two or more parties. Second, the agreement must cause an “injury to competition in the marketplace.”[13] Courts have found that there must be an injury to the relevant marketplace[14], where marketplace is defined as a “collection of products and geographic locations.”[15] Third, the agreement must restrain trade in interstate commerce.
c.     Analysis of a Section 1 Claim
If there is an agreement between two or more parties that restrains trade or affects interstate commerce, then it falls under Section 1 of the Act. Next, there must be an analysis as to whether an exemption applies to the agreement. If an exemption applies, then the agreement will not violate Section 1. The exemptions are Major League Baseball, the Statutory Labor Exemption, and the Non-Statutory Labor Exemption.
The first exemption is for Major League Baseball. In Federal Baseball Club v. National League, the Supreme Court ruled the Act did not apply to Major League Baseball.[16] In the majority opinion, Justice Holmes, classified baseball games as “purely state affairs.”[17] About 50 years later in Flood v. Kuhn, the Supreme Court reaffirmed Federal Baseball and noted that if baseball was to be brought within the Act, then Congress must act to affirmatively do so.[18] This exemption has stood the test of time, yet it is not without controversy.[19] [20]
Next, is the statutory labor exemption, which is primarily targeted to labor unions.[21] The Clayton Act provides a statutory basis for workers to eliminate competition among themselves regarding working conditions without fear of antitrust liability.[22]  Furthermore, the Norris La Guardia Act bars federal courts from granting injunctions against peaceful labor disputes.[23] Both of these statutes allow labor unions to go on strike and bargain with employers over working conditions, wages, and hours.[24]
The last exemption is the non-statutory labor exemption. This exemption, unlike the others, is applicable to Silver’s proposal. It gives collective bargaining preference over antitrust laws.[25] It states that any union-management agreement that was a product of good faith negotiation will not be subject to antitrust liability.[26]  This begs the question: What qualifies as a product of good faith negotiation? In Mackey v. NFL, the 8th circuit prescribed a set of elements to determine whether an agreement was a product of good faith negotiation. Mackey held that for the non-statutory labor exemption to apply, the restraint on trade must (1) primarily affect only the parties to the collective bargaining agreement; (2) concern a mandatory subject of collective bargaining[27]; and (3) be a product of bona fide arms’ length bargaining.[28]
If the non-statutory labor exemption applies, then the court will ask whether the agreement was an illegal restraint on trade. In examining whether the agreement is illegal, there are two categories to examine: a Per Se violation or a Rule of Reason analysis.[29] If the court finds the agreement is a per se violation, then the agreement is inherently adverse to competition and presumed invalid.[30] Price fixing and agreements to restrict output are examples of agreements that would be a per se violation.[31] Per se violations are adverse to competition and are what antitrust laws are supposed to prevent.[32] They are anti-competitive, and have no redeeming qualities.[33] Under a rule of reason analysis, the courts engage in a balancing test.[34] The courts will balance the pro-competitive and anti-competitive effects.[35] If the pro-competitive effects outweigh the anti-competitive effects, then the agreement will not violate Section 1.[36] However, if the anti-competitive effects outweigh the pro-competitive effects, then it will violate Section 1. The rule of reason analysis is often used for sport agreements.[37] This legal framework will be crucial to the potential developments that could take place during the 2017 CBA negotiations.
II.Applying Section 1 Analysis to Silver’s Vision
Adam Silver is looking to raise the minimum age limit from 19 to 20, but has stated he is willing to work with the NCAA “to give athletes a more fair deal.”[38] In exchange for this increase in the age limit, the NBA would subsidize college players in a multiple aspects. It appears Silver intends for the NCAA to bargain with the NBA and NBPA in 2017; after all, Silver says this needs to be a “three-way conversation.”[39] Silver’s aims are commendable, but may pose challenges to antitrust law and the non-statutory labor exemption.
From Silver’s comments, it seems like the NBA would be willing make an agreement with the NBPA and NCAA regarding the compensation of college basketball players, in exchange for increasing the minimum age limit. Essentially, this would be a three-party agreement that would look to create new regulations and guidelines for NCAA basketball. This agreement would subsidize the “basic necessities” of players, contribute to the “actual cost of attendance gap above what the players get for their scholarships,” and offer a more complete insurance plan.[40]
In a ruling from the District Court in Northern California in Edward O’Bannon v. NCAA, the court calculated that by the NCAA bylaws, most students get a “full grant in aid,” which is usually less than the “cost of attendance” and players have to find some means to fill that gap, unless an “unexpected special financial need” applies, which is rare.[41] In addition, this agreement would also allow NCAA basketball players to make money off their own names and likeness by making the NCAA abolish bylaws 15.1 and 12.4.1.1,[42] which keep players from accepting money from outside sources. Under an antitrust analysis, how would this agreement hold up? Furthermore, who would bring the lawsuit?
Analyzing the elements, there is an agreement between two or more parties (the NBA, NBPA, and the NCAA), so the first element of Section 1 is satisfied. The third element is also satisfied, as this agreement would most certainly affect interstate commerce. The NBA and NCAA do business in multiple states (games are telecast nationally, players are recruited nationally, and tickets to games are sold nationally).[43] For purposes of the second element, one should identify the relevant marketplace and injury, and then determine if the exemption applies. If the exemption does not apply, then one should examine whether the agreement can withstand antitrust law under a rule of reason analysis.
The relevant marketplace has been defined by the courts in terms of “products and geographical space.”[44] The products in this case could be “athletes” playing basketball in the United States (inclusive of NCAA and NBA basketball players) and they are also the most likely to challenge the agreement.[45] NCAA basketball players would challenge the agreement claiming it injures them by prohibiting them from playing professional basketball at the age of 19.[46] This agreement would hurt those players who would stand much to gain by playing in the NBA at the age of 19.[47] College players would normally not be able to attack an agreement restricting age[48] because most management-union agreements are legal due to the non-statutory labor exemption.[49] In this case, however, players may be able to attack the agreement on one of two grounds: (1) the NCAA is not a party to the collective bargaining relationship and (2) that it may not have been the product of bona fide arm’s-length bargaining. Both of these attacks are grounded in the idea that the agreement would not sufficiently pass the non-statutory labor exemption.
a.     Silver’s Agreement and the Non-Statutory Labor Exemption
In order for the agreement to be exempt pursuant to the non-statutory labor exemption, it must meet the Mackey test.[50] Under Mackey, the agreement must primarily affect only the parties to the collective bargaining agreement.[51] In Clarett v. National Football League, the 2nd Circuit ruled that prospective employees could not bring an antitrust suit because they were indirectly represented members of the bargaining unit.[52] This decision expanded the class of individuals considered to be parties to the bargaining unit.[53] However, Adam Silver’s proposal is different in that it has three parties negotiating, two managements (NBA and NCAA), and one union (NBPA). It expand the bargaining unit. Prior to Clarett, the parties to a collective bargaining unit would be a labor union and management.[54] Many District Courts have simply defined this requirement as adhering to the “collective bargaining framework.”[55] It is clear that the NBA (being represented by the owners) is the management and the NBPA (representing the players) is the union. However, how does the NCAA fit into this bargaining relationship?
In United Mine Workers of America v. Pennington, the Supreme Court stated that the, “the policy of the antitrust laws is clearly set against employer-union agreements seeking to prescribe labor standards outside the bargaining unit.”[56] The “collective bargaining relationship” is a narrow relationship between management and unions. The case suggests there is no room for the NCAA in the relationship, especially when one considers the effects that the NCAA bylaws have on parties outside the NBA and NBPA bargaining unit. The NCAA, by joining hands with the NBA and NBPA and targeting the one-and-done problem, would surely affect many parties (colleges, college coaches, and college conferences) which are not privy to the unique NBA and NBPA collective bargaining relationship. It’s possible the NCAA would not fit the collective bargaining relationship and the agreement would be unable avail itself of the non-statutory labor exemption.
Notwithstanding the failure of the agreement to meet the first criterion of Mackey, it would most likely meet the second criterion, being a mandatory subject of bargaining. Clarett established that eligibility rules to play a sport were mandatory subjects of bargaining.[57] However, in addition to not meeting the first requirement, there is an argument that the agreement would not be a product of “bona fide arm’s-length bargaining.” “Arm’s length” is defined as “dealings between two parties...who have roughly equal bargaining power.”[58] Upon comparing the revenue streams of NCAA basketball and the NBA, the NBA made approximately six times more in revenue than the NCAA in 2012 - 2013.[59] In Mackey, the 8th Circuit lends credibility to the District Court’s saying that “inadequate finances” may count as a factor in deciding the relative bargaining power of the parties.[60]
NCAA players could argue there is an “inherent disparity” in bargaining power and that the agreement was not the result of “bona fide arm’s-length bargaining.”[61] This may be a tough argument to make, because the NBA is not compelling the NCAA to enter into an agreement. However, the NBA would be making a decision that would yield massive benefits to NCAA basketball. This places the NCAA in a tough position to reject the agreement. In short, they may have more control over the bargaining process than the NCAA and NBPA combined and it could be argued that this agreement may not be the result of “bona fide arm’s-length bargaining,” and fail the third criterion in Mackey.
b.     Silver’s Agreement and the Rule of Reason
Since the agreement would not be exempt under the non-statutory labor exemption, it would be subject to a rule of reason analysis.[62] Here, the courts would deem an agreement not to violate Section 1 of the Act if the pro-competitive effects outweigh the anti-competitive effects.[63] On one hand, this seems like a fairly pro-competitive agreement because the NCAA would be abolishing bylaws that act as restraints, which would allow players to receive financial resources outside the “full grant in aid.” Furthermore, the NBA could argue that the restraint was no more restrictive than necessary to achieve a legitimate business interest. In raising the minimum age limit for draft eligibility, it would increase the quality of the on-court product, which is undoubtedly in the best interest of the league.
On the other hand, the agreement heightens the age of eligibility for the NBA draft and restricts 19 year olds from entering the league, which is anti-competitive. However, on balance this agreement seems to be fairly reasonable in that it allows college basketball players to receive compensation from the NBA, to receive a more complete insurance plan, and to take advantage of their names and likeness in the open market. It opens the marketplace and paves the way for NCAA basketball players to financially capitalize on their brand. In its entirety, it seems to be a pro-competitive agreement and would most likely stand the rule of reason analysis.
III. Conclusion
Adam Silver’s three-way conversation to provide compensation for NCAA basketball players would probably be unable to avail itself of the non-statutory labor exemption. If college or professional basketball players bring an action for injury, they should allege that the agreement does not primarily affect only the parties to the unique management-union collective bargaining relationship and that the restraint is not a product of bona fide arm’s-length bargaining. However, the restraint would probably prevail under a rule of reason analysis if it fails the Mackey test. Under the rule of reason analysis, the agreement is pro-competitive because it allows NCAA basketball players to capitalize on their own names and likeness, have a better insurance plan, and be able to receive payments to meet their basic necessities. Additionally, the NBA would be able to offer a legitimate business interest (improving the quality of the players on NBA teams, and thus the league) for why they would raise the draft eligibility age.
If Adam Silver has his way, it will not be without any legal challenges or questions. This agreement could solve the “one-and-done” problem, but it is more ambitious and noble than that. Adam Silver feels the need for the NBA to take the lead on a key moral issue, but it will most certainly test the limits of antitrust law and the non-statutory labor exemption.




[1] See Myron Medcalf, The Unknown Future of one-and-done, ESPN.com, (Jun. 27, 2012), http://espn.go.com/mens-college-basketball/story/_/id/8101090/the-unknown-future-nba-one-done-rule-men-college-basketball.
[2]  Nat’l Basketball Association, Collective bargaining Agreement between the NBA and the NBA Players Association, Art. X, Sec. 1, § (b)(i), (2011).
[3] Brandon Jennings and Emmanuel Mudiay.
[4] Zach Harper, Commissioner Adam Silver still wants age limit of 20 for draft eligibility, CBS Sports, (Nov. 24, 2014), http://www.cbssports.com/nba/eye-on-basketball/24838071/commissioner-adam-silver-still-wants-age-limit-of-20-for-draft-eligibility.
[5] Id.
[6] Darren Rovell, Adam Silver: ‘3-Way Conversation’, ESPN.com, (Apr. 9, 2014), http://espn.go.com/nba/story/_/id/10758585/nba-commissioner-adam-silver-says-subsidizing-ncaa-athletes-possibility.
[7] “A student-athlete shall not be eligible to participate in intercollegiate athletics if he or she receives financial aid that exceeds the value of the cost of attendance as defined in Bylaw 15.02.2. A student-athlete may receive institutional financial aid based on athletics ability (per Bylaw 15.02.4.1), outside financial aid for which athletics participation is a major criterion (per Bylaw 15.2.6.4) and educational expenses awarded per Bylaw 15.2.6.5 up to the value of a full grant-in-aid, plus any other financial aid unrelated to athletics ability up to the cost of attendance.”
[8] “Such compensation may not include any remuneration for value or utility that the student-athlete may have for the employer because of the publicity, reputation, fame or personal following that he or she has obtained because of athletics ability.”
[9] NCAA regulations and bylaws comprise of a 400 page book. This makes it extremely difficult for students and member schools to stay in compliance.
[10] Id.
[11] 15 U.S.C. § 1 (1890).
[12] See generally The United States Department of Justice, Antitrust Laws and You, http://www.justice.gov/atr/about/antitrust-laws.html (last visited Mar. 30, 2015).
[13] See Jarod Bona, Antitrust Injury and the Classic Antitrust Case of Brunswick Corp v. Pueblo Bowl-O-Mat, The Antitrust Attorney Blog (Nov. 20, 2014), http://www.theantitrustattorney.com/2014/11/20/antitrust-injury-classic-antitrust-case-brunswick-corp-v-pueblo-bowl-o-mat/.
[14] Brunswick Corp. v. Pueblo Bowl-O-Mat, Inc., 429 U.S. 477, 488–9 (1977). Also the plaintiff bringing the antitrust lawsuit must be injured by the type of injury that the antitrust laws were meant to prevent and that the defendant’s actions must have caused some injury to the plaintiff. William Holmes and Melissa Mangiaracina, Antitrust Law Handbook, (last updated Oct. 2014).
[15] Jonathan Baker, Market Definition: An Analytical Overview, 74 Antitrust L. J. 129, 130 (2007).
[16] Federal Baseball Club v. National League, 259 U.S. 200, 209 (1922).
[17] Id. at 209.
[18] Flood v. Kuhn, 407 U.S. 258, 281 (1972).
[19] It is clear that baseball is interstate commerce and is not just purely a state affair.
[20] Flood v. Kuhn, 407 U.S. 258,  281 (1972) (Justice Blackmun even referred to the MLB exemption as an anomaly).
[21] See generally Randall Marks, Labor and Antitrust: Striking a Balance Without Balancing, 35 Am. U. Law Rev. 699, 717 (1986).
[22] United States v. Hutcheson, 312 U.S. 219, 236 (1941).
[23]  29 U.S.C. 101 (1932).
[24] Christopher Andrews, Labor Exemption to the Antitrust Laws, Shielding an Anticompetitive Provision Devised by an Employer Group in its Own Interest: McCourt v. California Sports, Inc, 21 Boston College L. Rev., 680 (1980).
[25] See John Mackey v. National Football League, 543 F.2d 606 (8th Cir. 1976).
[26] See id.
[27] Id. at 614. The Court in Mackey said that mandatory subjects of collective bargaining are “wages, hours, and other terms of and conditions of employment.”.
[28] Mackey, 543 F.2d 606, 614 (8th Cir. 1976).
[29] Cornell University School of Law, Antitrust: An Overview, https://www.law.cornell.edu/wex/antitrust (last visited Apr. 1, 2014).
[30] See id.
[31] See id.
[32] See id.
[33] See id.
[34] Cornell University School of Law, Antitrust: An Overview, https://www.law.cornell.edu/wex/antitrust (last visited Apr. 1, 2014).
[35] See id.
[36] See id.
[37] Gabriel Feldman, Antitrust Versus Labor Law in Professional Sports: Balancing the Scales after Brady v. NFL and Anthony v. NBA, 45 U. C. Davis. L. Rev. 1221, 1222 (2012).
[38] Darren Rovell, Adam Silver: ‘3-Way Conversation’, ESPN.com, (Apr. 9, 2014), http://espn.go.com/nba/story/_/id/10758585/nba-commissioner-adam-silver-says-subsidizing-ncaa-athletes-possibility.
[39] Id.
[40] Id.
[41] Edward O’Bannon v. Nat’l Collegiate Athletic Ass’n, No. C 09-3329 CW, at 20 (N.D. C. Aug. 8, 2014).
[42] Supra note 7.
[43] David Hughes, O’Bannon v. NCAA: Say Goodbye to the Cinderella Story,  22 The Sports Lawyers Journal 261, 262 (2015).
[44] Robert Morris and Thomas Jorde, Antitrust Market Definition: An Integrated Approach, 72 California Law Review 3, 4 (1984).
[45] Perhaps, in the broadest sense, the product could be collegiate and professional basketball games.
[46] The important thing is that players may see a larger benefit in playing in the NBA at 19 as opposed to playing at 20 and having some extra benefits in the NCAA.
[47] In fact, current NBA veterans against such measures, assuming they would be able to show an injury, may be another potential class of litigants to bring suit on antitrust grounds.
[48] Clarett v. National Football League, 369 F.3d 124, 143 (2d. Cir. 2004) (explaining that the NFL may have an age restriction eligibility rule for players entering the NFL draft because it was exempted and bargained for under the non-statutory labor exemption). Michael Scheinkman, Running Out of Bounds: Over-Extending the Labor Antitrust Exemption in Clarett v. National Football League, 79 St. John’s L. Rev. 733, 757-8 (2005) (Clarett was not an outsider to the collective bargaining unit because the “NFLPA has the power and discretion to prioritize certain groups of employees, which includes favoring veteran players over aspiring rookies).
[49] Mackey, 543 F.2d 606, 614 (8th Cir. 1976) (citing the various requirements that agreements must meet in order to be considered exempt under the non-statutory labor exemption).
[50] The MLB and statutory labor exemptions do apply in this context because it does not concern MLB and the non-statutory labor exemption is generally applied over the statutory labor exemption with regard to sports.
[51] Mackey, 543 F.2d 606, 614 (8th Cir. 1976).
[52] Supra note 48, Scheinkman, at 758.
[53] It is clear that the NCAA does not fall into this classification.
[54] United Mine Workers of America v. Pennington, 381 U.S. 657, 668 (1965).
[55] Brady v. National Football League, 779 F. Supp 2d 992, 1040 (D. Minn. 2011); Independent Entertainment Group, Inc. v National Basketball Ass’n, 853 F. Supp. 333,340 (C.D. Cal 1994).
[56] Pennington, 381 U.S. 657, 668 (1965).
[57] Clarett v. National Football League, 369 F.3d 124, 139-40 (2d. Cir. 2004).
[58] Black’s Law Dictionary 44 (3rd Edition, 2006).
[59] Mark Alesia, NCAA Approaching Billion Per Year Amid Challenges by Players, Indiana Star (Mar. 27, 2014) http://www.indystar.com/story/news/2014/03/27/ncaa-approaching-billion-per-year-amid-challenges-players/6973767/; Park Summers, The Donald Sterling Dilemma, WordPress.com (Sep. 22, 2014) https://parksummers.wordpress.com/2014/09/23/the-donald-sterling-dilemma/.
[60] Mackey, 543 F.2d 606, 615 (8th Cir. 1976).
[61] This assumes the disparity in the NCAA and NBA revenue remains the same in 2017.
[62] The rule of reason analysis is most likely applied to sports. Also, there does not seem to be anything per se illegal about this agreement on its face.
[63] Cornell University School of Law, Antitrust: An Overview, https://www.law.cornell.edu/wex/antitrust (last visited Apr. 1, 2014).

No comments:

Post a Comment